‘The building up of the money-to-GDP ratios is both a strength and a weakness of China’s financial system.’ Discuss.
In China there has been an extensive build up in the money-to-GDP[1]
ratios which has been a strength of the financial system in times of crisis but
may also constitute a weakness in the long term due to effects on the quality
of loans of the Chinese system and inefficiency of resource allocation.
First of all, let’s identify the money-to-GDP ratios. In the
case of China there tend to be 2 main ratios discussed in the literature,
namely the M1-to-GDP ratio, and the M2-to-GDP ratio. M1 is ‘narrow money’,
defined as ‘currency i.e. banknotes and coins, plus overnight deposits’ (OECD, 2012) and M2 is ‘broad
money’, defined as ‘currency plus demand and saving deposits’ (Naughton, 2007, p. 451) .
Firstly it should be noted that cross-country analysis of the
money-to-GDP ratio is limited as no international standard was implemented
until the year 2000 by the IMF (OECD, 2012) . Furthermore,
measures of M2 in China may tend to ‘underestimate true money holdings’ due to
the exclusion of some ‘deposit-like liabilities of deposit-taking institutions’
from the measurements according to Song (2007) and, according to Liang (2007),
an inability to keep up with the rapid changes the capital markets in China are
undergoing (Wu, 2009, p.
4) .
The measurement of GDP in China has also been criticised by some calling for it
to be marked downwards to make up for complaints made even by Zhu Rongji, in
the year 2000, of rampant ‘falsification
and exaggeration’ (Rawski, 2001) . Moreover, analyses
from within China often ignore or contradict official statistics (Rawski, 2001) . Therefore there must
be caution applied when using the ratios.
Leaving the statistical complications aside, the implications
of the build up in the money-to-GDP ratio must be assessed. The build up in M2
indicates an increased monetisation in the Chinese economy. That is money is
demanded more for transactions than before. To maintain growth of monetisation,
the money must be absorbed without causing excessive inflationary pressures (Lodhi, 2005) . M2 has grown from
32% of GDP in 1978 (Naughton, 2007) to 178% in 2009,
internationally the highest (Chen, Ma, & Tang, 2011) . It shows a high
savings rates and the possibility of forced savings in bank deposits due to
high growth coupled with few investment opportunities for residents (a high
concentration of financial institutions being state-controlled banks) and a
requirement to save due to a lack of strong social safety nets (Chen, Ma,
& Tang, 2011) .
Household savings increased from 1978 as 6% of GDP to 77% of GDP in 2005 (Naughton,
2007) .
These bank savings are thus used for investment purposes by the government and
state-owned enterprises (SOEs) with via bank lending and drive financial growth
(Chen, Ma,
& Tang, 2011) .
This may seem a strength as it can help fuel investment. However, this growth
is not necessarily as efficient as it could be and may show an inherent
weakness in the system in a lack of domestic demand.
The increased monetisation may also be a weakness where inefficient
loans are a systemic problem. In particular the apparent safety net of the
government guaranteeing loans to banks may be a cause of inefficient investment
allocation in China (Zhang, 2012) . The growth in the
money which came with the credit stimulus of 4 trillian yuan of the government
gave excess liquidity to banks which they could not give back to the central
bank (which would be a way to ‘mop-up’ excess liquidity), was trapped in the
inter-bank market and therefore was lent out as credit (Zhang, 2012) . The increase in
loans to local governments and state-owned enterprises stimulated the
government’s planned construction projects (Zhang, 2012) . However, there are
some warnings that, due to the lower interest rates which led to the lack of
access to banks for the more efficient private sector, there is a high
possibility that non-performing-loans (NPLs) will once again build up, as they
did before the removal of the NPLs of the big 4 banks via asset management
companies (AMCs) (Zhang, 2012) (IMF, 2011) . Then again there
has been a strong fall in the number of NPLs in recent years (IMF, 2011) which may be a sign
of an improved lending system (i.e. better risk management, etc) through
reforms, and the removal of guarantee for some SOEs which led to their
bankruptcy in the 1990s, which could mean that the rise in NPLs will not be as
great as it was previously. The weakness caused by the excess liquidity on
China’s financial system is uncertain but the risk of further inundation of
NPLs cannot be ignored. The recent influx of liquidity to the inter-bank markets
will foster further the ‘addicted to investment’ (Zhang, 2012)
growth pattern, which can be a problem and weakness. The problem of a lack of
domestic demand and increased investment may cause ‘welfare loss for consumers,
overcapacity of production, and inefficient resource allocation’ (Zhang, 2012) . The long-term plan
of restructuring the financial and economic system has been put off due to the (required)
stimulus package of the global financial crisis according to Zhang (2012). According
to some pessimists the ‘abnormally high’ M2-to-GDP ratio shows that if
restructuring is not achieved and the threat of NPLs not lessened then there
will be a collapse in the system and hyper-inflation (Yu, 2000) . The strength of the
high savings ratio as a fuel for money-to-GDP ratio increases and therefore development
investment, as well as for anti-crisis stimulus packages to alleviate
bottlenecks (Woo, 2003) , may be seen to be
counteracted by the inefficient allocation of resources and the build up of NPLs
in the Chinese banks in the late 1990s. This weakness was to some extent
overcome with the selling off of these debts and the lowering of banks’ NPLs
and perhaps the NPL weakness is less than perceived. However, the recent
stimulus package has reignited the fears of NPLs reoccurring. This may be
improved by the increased financial efficiency which may be achieved through
financial standardisation as outlined in the 12th Five Year Plan (Li, 2011) .
A potential strength of the financial system is its ability
to be used in macroeconomic policy, through the money supply. However, there is
some evidence of a ‘stop-go’ process in the Chinese states’ handling of the
macroeconomic policy. By applying a tight or contractionary monetary policy
(less credit made available for lending), the Chinese government would lower
M1-to-GDP and therefore stifle inflation. Conversely, in the situation of
deflation, a loose or expansionary policy (increasing of M1-to-GDP ratio, more
credit available) would allow the government to regain price stability (Woo, 2003) . When the monetary
policy was applied in the 1990s while the fall in M1 caused by the tightened
monetary policy did restrict inflation, the fear of a rebound of the inflation
led the government to ‘overkill’ the situation and cause deflation (Woo, 2003) . To get out of the
situation, a policy of loose monetary policy was used and M1 shot back up,
however, there was not an accompanying mass of inflation, although inflation would
return. This is because excess liquidity (increased money to GDP ratio) is a
cause of inflation in China (Zhang C. , 2009) , but in 1997 when
the reflationary policy was applied, the banks were unlikely to lend due to an
unwillingness by banks to lend due to suspected retaliation for acquiring NPLs
(while SOE lending was riskier than to private enterprise, an NPL from a private
enterprise had negative political implications and so lending altogether
dropped) and this was not changed until
bank managers were ascertained that an increase in the NPL ratio would not be
blamed on them (Woo, 2003) . From then until
2007 the inflation rate was kept in bounds[2]
and the new reforms have led to China being able to apply a better
macroeconomic strategy to effect inflation although this is somewhat limited by
the exchange rate regime since the value of the currency can’t fluctuate
according to macro shocks (OECD, 2010) . In fact the
reliance on manipulating the money supply can be seen as a weakness in its
stop-go approach to causing and relieving inflation and deflation, respectively.
This is backed up by the previous record of the Chinese government in the 1990s
to overkill on tightened macroeconomic policy which led to deflation (Woo, 2003) . The weakness of the
limited macroeconomic policy of the Chinese government underpins a weakness in
the financial system which is halfway through restructuring (Zhang, 2012) (Woo, 2003) .
Another advantage that has occurred from the financial system
and the money-to-GDP ratio has been a high rate of seigniorage (Chen, Ma,
& Tang, 2011) .
Seigniorage is the “the
supplement of real revenue accruing to authorities (government and central bank)
from the monopoly they have on money supply” (Debray, 1998) . Monetization and
Financial Deepening (that is the increased use of financial intermediaries)
both have had an effect in making a higher seigniorage possible in China’s case (Debray, 1998) . In fact how this has occurred is
through the high money-to-GDP ratio without excess inflation (constantly within
20%). In general the countries which have high seigniorage are countries which
experience hyper-inflation, but China has had low inflation. Furthermore, the
forced savings mentioned earlier has meant that, despite facing depreciation on
their saving the household saving have in general increased (Debray, 1998) . In 1988-89 when
there was a strong possibility of switching from accounts due to panic buying
and inflation due to a perceived volatility of prices (Bramall,
2009) ,
the indexation to inflation of interest rates on savings deposits helped
prevent it (Debray, 1998) . Tight monetary
policy also helped overcome the inflation, though it led to deflation and a
renewed loose monetary policy leading to further inflation from from 2000-2007 (Zhang C. ,
2009) .
The effect of seigniorage depends on the M1-to-GDP ratio and here we see what
it implicates for the Chinese economy. The potential revenue accrued by
seigniorage by the government or central bank was relatively high while
monetization was a driving force of money expansion, but between 1993-97 the
potential revenue lessened (Debray, 1998) . Debray accounts
this to a ‘slow down of monetization’ (Debray, 1998) which will mean a
fall in the revenue accumulated by money creation for the Chinese Government
and/or central bank (Debray, 1998) . This fall in
monetisation may be contestable however, considering the further increases in
M1 which have occurred, particularly if they have still occurred without
inflation, which it has although the level of inflation had increased with the
increased liquidity (Zhang C. , 2009) . This may be a
potential strength, or at least was a strength of the build up of money-to-GDP
ratios.
Overall, the state-dominance of the banking sector seems to
be a weakness in the financial system, and its use of the monetisation and
savings for investment and policy are the main cause of difficulty in the
splitting of banking system as other government revenues are small compared to
many countries (Woo, 2003) . The closed market has
meant that the banks to not have an ‘internationally competitive business
model’ and that innovation is not fully developed (Chen, Ma,
& Tang, 2011) .
The stock market itself also is seen more as a policy market, government led,
however an immature bond market has grown significantly recently, although
problems still remain (Chen, Ma, & Tang, 2011) . The money markets are also greatly affected by
the state-run banks whose movements strongly affect the interest rates and
therefore the market cannot function without being affected by the policy
biases of these banks (as shown earlier – interest rate too low for private
enterprise to loan) (Chen, Ma, & Tang, 2011) . However, the
control of government over investment cannot always be shunned simply as
inefficient. The concerns of the government for development will also hold some
sway over the pattern of investment. Here the choice of the government to use
increasing money-to-GDP ratios to fund investment in critical construction and
infrastructure in lesser developed China may be considered a strategic long
term goal for improving overall development even if returns are not perfect (Laurenceson
& Chai, 2001) .
With growth which outstrips the original costs via increased savings due to
increased incomes and thus savings, then China may be able to pay off (again)
the NPLs which it accumulates from investment. Overall this shows that the
monetisation may be a strength of the financial system in terms of China’s
development, should policy-bias still be established.
Overall, it seems that the building up of money-to-GDP ratios
has been a strength of the Chinese financial system in many ways. It has helped
the government direct investment, although this has led to inefficient SOEs
being financed even when they should go bust. Although this has to some extent
subsided, it appears that the risk remains that NPLs will reoccur. The most
dangerous problem may be that the weakness of low domestic demand is not fixed
due to reliance on the savings for capital accumulation. However, should China
manage to improve the social safety net it is possible that this will be overcome.
The increase in money supply will become a problem when inflation it causes is
extremely high, and seigniorage is lessened. Until that time it may be possible
to say that the build up of money to GDP ratios is more of a strength than a
weakness, particularly should reforms improve the ability of banks to lend with
better risk management. Then again, there may be further strength in the
government’s ability to direct investment to long-term goals with a low return
which are important in its development strategy. The strength should not be
overstated of monetisation however, as the increase shows growth in GDP but not
growth in wealth, simply the use of money to buy and sell those things that
were not bought and sold previously and thus not counted in GDP (Mu, 2007) . However the effect
of seigniorage must be seen as a strength. Overall it seems the strengths can
outweigh the weaknesses, although with the weaknesses fixed it could be an even
greater strength.
Wordcount: 2342
Bibliography
Bramall, C. (2009). Chinese Economic Development.
Abingdon: Routledge.
Chen, Y., Ma, Y., & Tang, K. (2011, February).
The Chinese Financial System at the Dawn of the 21st century: An Overview. AESTIMATIO,
The IEB International Journal of Finance, 2-41.
Debray, G. B. (1998). MONEY DEMAND AND THE
POTENTIAL OF SEIGNIORAGE IN CHINA. Retrieved from www.cerdi.org:
www.cerdi.org/uploads/ed/1998/1998.21.pdf
Huang, Y., Wang, X., & Hua, X. (2010). What
Determine China’s Inflation? Retrieved from http://www.ceauk.org.uk/:
http://www.ceauk.org.uk/2010-conference-papers/full-papers/Wang-Xun-CEA-final.pdf
IMF. (2011). People's Republic of China:
Financial System Stability Assessment. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund.
Laurenceson, J., & Chai, J. (2001). State Banks
and Economic Development in China. Journal of International Development,
211-225.
Li, D. (2011). Standardization Strategy enhancing
the competitiveness of Financial Industry in China. Retrieved from
www.cspress.cn:
www.cspress.cn/config/newsfiles/2011-07.../finance%20industry.pdf
Lodhi, M. A. (2005). Financial Sector
Development. Retrieved from www.sbp.org.pk:
www.sbp.org.pk/publications/FSA/2005/Chapter_8.pdf
Mu, Y. (2007). Unveiling China’s Economic
Miracle. Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com:
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=999955
Naughton, B. (2007). The Chinese Economy:
Transition and Growth. London: The MIT Press.
OECD. (2010). Economic Survey of China, 2010.
www.oecd.org/china: ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT.
OECD. (2012, April 14). Monetyary Aggregates -
Data and Methods. Retrieved from http://stats.oecd.org:
http://stats.oecd.org/mei/default.asp?lang=e&subject=14
Rawski, T. (2001). What is happening to China’s GDP
statistics? China Economic Review, 347-354.
Woo, W. T. (2003). Confronting restructuring and
stability. In S. Yao, & X. Liu, Sustaining China's Economic Growth in
the Twenty-First Century (pp. 13-40). London: RoutledgeCurzon.
Wu, G. (2009). Broad Money Demand and Asset
Substitution in China. IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund,
Asia and Pacific Department.
Yu, Y. (2000). China's Deflation during the Asian
Financial Crisis, and Reform of the International Financial System. ASEAN
Economic Bulletin, Vol. 17, No. 2, THE ASIAN FINANCIAL CRISIS:
Hindsight,Insight and Foresight, 163-174.
Zhang, C. (2009). Excess Liquidity, Inflation and
the Yuan Appreciation: What Can China Learn from Recent History? The World
Economy, 998-1018.
Zhang, W. (2012). China's anti-crisis macro-economic
management. In J. H. Chang, China's Crisis Management (pp. 1-23).
Abingdon: Routledge.
No comments:
Post a Comment