To what extent has
agricultural performance improved during the transition from Socialism in China
and in Post-Soviet states? Is the improvement due to decollectivisation?
Agricultural
performance has improved massively in China during its transition from
Socialism, but this has been due to a number of factors of which
decollectivisation is but one. Furthermore, in Post-Soviet states (FSU
countries) the link between decollectivisation and improved agricultural
performance is less than clear.
Firstly, in Figure 1,
China’s growth in agricultural output is seen to clearly grow more quickly from
either 1978 or 1981 onwards. This growth first appears in the period of
decollectivisation in China, which occurred between 1977 and 1983 and thus a
consensus has been made on the correlation with a move to family farming [Bramall, 2009] . In fact, during
this period there was a surge in production in almost all agricultural outputs
and agricultural growth rates were 4.6 per cent between 1976-80 and 10.1 per
cent from 1980-84, much higher than the 2.5 per cent average from 1965-76 [Bramall,
2009] [Naughton,
2007, ページ:
242-3] .
In Figure 2, the Central-Asia FSU countries agricultural output is shown to in
some cases fall, i.e. Kazakhstan, Ukraine and Russia [Swinnen, Van
Herck, Vranken, 2009] , and in other cases shows modest growth
at best from 1992, although there is some picking up towards the late 2000s.
Uzbekistan’s growth seems to be fairly strong from about 2003 onwards after a
period of stagnation. Uzbekistan at that time had far from fully implemented
agricultural reforms [Rozelle Swinnen, 2004] and acts only to
remove from the idea that decollectivisation itself is a cause of improved
agricultural output in the transition from Socialism to Capitalism. Then again,
there has been a general improvement in gross agricultural output in the
transitional countries after the initial dip, although the amount is still
below the pre-reform era for many FSU areas as seen in Figure 3 and
Agricultural Labour Productivity in the Central Asia region has only recovered
recently [Swinnen, Van Herck, Vranken,
2009] .
On this data alone it would appear that the move to decollectivise itself
cannot be seen as the only factor.
Figure 1 FAOSTAT | © FAO Statistics Division 2012 | 10 March 2012
Figure 2 FAOSTAT | © FAO Statistics Division 2012 | 10
March 2012
Figure 3 Evolution
of the Gross Agricultural Output (GOA) [Swinnen, Van Herck, Vranken, 2009, ページ: 2]
One argument may be that it is not the decollectivisation that matters so
much as to how the process of the transition from Socialism itself is managed. There
is a clear difference between Chinese gradual transition and the FSU countries’
transition in which the Communist governments collapsed, or were affected by
the Russian collapse. In the case of China, the state government still governed
the input and output of the farms, that is, the state controlled sales to the
farmers of inputs such as fertilizer and procured grain at a set price [Naughton,
2007] .
It is possible this control helped to steady the uncertainty of farmers in the
move to a more market orientated system, as compared to in the FSU countries
where uncertainty and price volatility negatively affected farmers in some
cases [Sušjan Redek, 2008] due to subsidy cuts
and price liberalization which made prices of inputs unaffordable (Swinnen, Van
Herck, & Vranken, 2009) or the institutions
for the necessary inputs were non-existent (Tyers, 1994,
p. 24) .
This could further be tied to the problem of a lack of political will and the
change in governments, which led to uncertainties in the decollectivisation
process in many FSU countries and even within different regions (Mathijs &
Swinnen, 1998) .
There are some cases where laws were changed in land redistribution by
successive governments in Bulgaria for example, and in the Central Asian FSU
countries there were considerable barriers to restructuring of collective farms
as far as 1998 (Mathijs & Swinnen, 1998) . This, if compared
with China shows that some steadiness in the rural institutions along with
market orientation through decollectivisation (as well as a clear political
will seen by the decisiveness of China’s move to family farming, where
decollectivisation was carried out despite protest against decollectivisation
in some regions (Bramall, 2009) ) has a positive
impact on agricultural performance in a transition from Socialism and helped
play a role in the improving Chinese performance and the decline in FSU
countries’ performance.
To further analyze the impact of decollectivisation on the agricultural
performance of transition countries, some of the theoretical arguments concerning
collective farming must be looked at. Two in particular are of specific
interest: a) the inverse relationship of farm size and yield, and b) the
problem of worker incentives on collective farms and free riding or work
shirking. The first argument is that farms cannot take advantage of economies
of scale (Bramall, 2009) . The evidence is
unclear, but Rakshit shows that through a process of capital intensification
some farms in West Bengal are subject to economies of scale (Rakshit,
2011) .
This goes hand in hand with the evidence of large-scale farms transformed from
collectives in Hungary in the transition period and their quicker recovery of
average yields, compared the slow recovery of countries which switched to a smaller,
family farm style with less input access (Swinnen, Van Herck, &
Vranken, 2009) .
Rather than the switch to family farming on small plots of land being a cause
for Chinese agriculture performance increases, it is possible that, where
inputs were affordable, i.e. where there was a movement towards mechanization
causing protest (Bramall, 2009) , the forced
decollectivisation in fact acted as a constraint on Chinese agricultural
performance in the transition. That said, in poorer Central Asian FSUs, the
decollectivisation may have had a positive impact, if adequate institutions and
political will had existed, if the mechanization process was not possible
immediately (as suggested by (Mathijs & Swinnen, 1998) ). Furthermore, the
transformation to smaller production teams in China and evidence of Indian and
Vietnamese cooperatives/collectivities show that smaller production units/cooperatives,
especially which are made up of workers with social bonds, work more
productively (Agarwal, 2010) (Wolz &
Duong, 2008) (Naughton,
2007)
although a general consensus seems to be that collectives tend to accrue
economies of scale in risk management at the very least, through group
marketing, infrastructure investment and also greater bargaining power and a
greater ability to secure credit (Agarwal, 2010) (Mathijs &
Swinnen, 1998) .
This point ties into the second problem of incentive structures which seems
a far more important issue in the case of China (Bramall,
2009) .
The most obvious problem is the coercive nature of the collectives in the
Socialist countries (Agarwal, 2010) but another problem
to the incentives was the temptation to shirk. This is a problem in larger
collective farming groups seen in the varying measures of work point allocation
and where production teams of communes were larger there was more incentive to
shirk as social pressures aren’t as strong an incentive (Agarwal,
2010) .
Also in Vietnam, where the collectives were allowed to transform into
cooperatives, the move from larger cooperatives to smaller ones may highlight
this shirking problem as a factor (Wolz & Duong, 2008) . In the Chinese
collectives, there were in general work point allocation systems of piece-rate,
i.e. based on what or how much is done, or time-rate, i.e. based on time spent
doing the work (Li, 2009) . The implementation
and effectiveness depended a lot on leadership, with some leaders’ leadership
helping to ‘stimulate production, provided that there was an identity of
interest between the leaders and the led’ (Li, 2009, p.
207) .
Nevertheless there were often problems of shirking (Bramall,
2009) (Li, 2009) . This came from a
difficulty of supervision of workers on farms due to large size and difficulty
in disaggregating the work done through the output which could be adversely
affected by weather and other issues which were difficult to measure (Bramall,
2009) .
However there are some gains for peasants which may have offset the
disincentives induced by these and the coercive aspect of the collectives along
the lines of health and education gains, social security, and the removal of ‘exploitative
class relations which typified the Republican countryside’ (Bramall, 2009, pp. 242-3) . Furthermore,
Bramall points out that during the decollectivisation process in China,
collective farms were no less productive than the family farms which they ran
alongside, which were relatively few in any case at the start of the fast
growth period (Bramall, 2009) . This plus the fact
that the FSU countries agricultural output and labour productivity has yet to
reach pre-reform levels in some countries (Swinnen, Van Herck, &
Vranken, 2009)
seem to show that neither the incentive issue and inverse relationship factors are
necessarily significant constraints on collective farming and so do not show
that decollectivisation was an important factor in improved agricultural
production in China or the FSU countries in transition from Socialism. Neither
of these factors is as important as the previous institutions problem in
explaining the agricultural performances in transition from Socialism.
Land rights, or the lack of, may be somewhat correlated with the
agricultural performance. In China the land rights of the farmers were to some
extent changed through the decollectivisation process, with land leases being
given in many areas for as long as fifty years (Naughton, 2007) . This contrasts with
the FSU countries where decollectivisation was slow and in some countries private
land rights were not approved as a policy, such as Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan,
as far as 1998 (Mathijs & Swinnen, 1998) . Where private land
ownership was allowed in Kyrgyzstan and Kazakhstan, growth in agricultural output
is still limited when looking at 1992 as the first year, even compared to the
other Central Asian FSU countries. This may be explained by the other countries
starting from a lower per capita GDP where extra capital leads to a greater
increase in production in theory, although the model is contested by some economists,
such as Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) (Knight,
Loayza, & Villanueva, 1993) . Then again, if you
look from 1999 onwards, the gains in output by Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan occur
far quicker than the other central Asian FSU countries which maybe a sign that
land ownership, or long land leasing as seen in China, has a positive effect on
agricultural performance. This is supported further by Naughton who shows that once
free to allocate labour themselves, farmers worked harder for less time, and
switched to less labour-intensive crops, even if the returns were less, and
this while overall output was increasing (Naughton, 2007) . There is some
evidence of land security leading to more long-term investments in Vietnam, however,
although the more efficient allocation of inputs may be shown in some evidence,
a number of other factors including social and political structures also play a
part, either as a constraint or as an accelerator, as seen in China by region
and Vietnam (Hare, 2008) .
Nevertheless, the evidence shown in agricultural growth rates plays out to
this, where less secure terms of land ownership in the FSU countries (except Kyrgyzstan
and Kazakhstan) is correlated with lesser agricultural performance
(improvement), except in Turkmenistan which didn’t accept private land
ownership in 1998 (Mathijs & Swinnen, 1998) , although this is an
oil exporting country which may affect this outcome (Dowling &
Wignaraja, 2006) [1].
By this I would conclude that steady, long term land rights as given through
the decollectivisation process, when coupled by proper/steady institutions and
political structure, may have had a long-term effect on the agricultural
performances of countries in transition from Socialism.
What may have been more important however, is a change in the terms of
trade in the USSR and the Soviet States and China, and also the grain first
policy of Maoist China. The emphasis on grain production as a whole in Maoist
China, although less so in late Maoist China, acted as a constraint on
agriculture, with areas unsuited to grain production being used to fulfill
collective quotas (Bramall, 2009) . While there are
signs throughout the Maoist period that this ‘monoculture’ declined, it is
still a key factor in the lower growth of the period (Bramall,
2009) .
Perhaps more important was the role of
agriculture as a ‘net-contributor to industrialization in the 1950s’ (Bramall,
2009, p. 245)
and also through the late Maoist period through ‘unequal exchange, or a shift
in ‘double factorial terms of trade – the terms of trade adjusted for sectoral
productivity’ (Bramall,
2009, p. 246) .
This shift meant that due to low profitability it was difficult for the farms
to invest in modern inputs, which at any rate were not being created due to a
lack of investment, with investment in heavy industry and military being
significant objectives (i.e. the Third Front Policy). The terms of trade from
1978 were in fact improved substantially in 1978, which may have had an
important contribution (Bramall, 2009) as shown in the next
paragraph. In the Soviet Union, a similar strategy was used, which may have
left FSU countries’ farms with little profits for investment and development (Carter &
Zhu, 2009, p. 3) ,
similar to the Chinese situation pre-1978. However, the collapse of subsidies
as a factor in the collapse of production in the FSU countries (Mathijs &
Swinnen, 1998)
contradicts this to some extent.
In fact, the main argument to explain the growth in China and lack of
growth in the FSU countries may be the introduction of the Green Revolution in
China from 1978 onwards, after a shift in the term of trade more favourable to
agriculture allowed the farmers to invest in greater amounts of fertilizer and
new high yielding varieties (HYV) of seeds (Bramall, 2009) . Furthermore, under
Maoist rule an irrigation system, a typical requirement of the Green Revolution
package, was well set up throughout China (Bramall, 2009) . Bramall argues that the extent that this is an
important factor is shown in the difference in Vietnamese improved agricultural
performance and Chinese performance. While Vietnam has increased its
productivity efficiently, the same chance under its much short collectivised
system did not allow it to have the same extent of an irrigated system (Bramall,
2009) .
Furthermore, Vietnam’s HYV seed research came relatively later than China’s (Hossain, Ut,
& Janaiah, 2003) . As for the FSU countries, there was no
such boost to agricultural inputs availability or income through better prices,
which to some extent explains the poorer performance and supports the argument
that the decollectivisation may have been a relatively small factor in the
improvement agricultural performance. The use of ‘inferior tools’ in the FSU
countries and the lack of availability of the necessary inputs due to
institutional and political instability (Mathijs & Swinnen, 1998) further supports this.
In conclusion, the terms of trade and inability to mechanise due to instability
and an unclear process of change of FSU countries’ institutions affected the
agricultural performance to start with in FSU countries, while land rights may
also have been an influential factor in the later stages in some of the faster
recovering countries. However, the rapid growth in China which occurred
concurrently with the decollectivisation process may have had more to do with a
Green Revolution process, directly affected by an extensive irrigation system
available in China.
Word-count: 2337/2920
Bibliography
Agarwal, B. (2010, February 27). Rethinking
Agricultural Production Collectivities. Economic and Political WEEKLY,
pp. 64-78.
Bramall, C. (2009). Collective Farming. In C.
Bramall, Chinese Economic Development (pp. 213-260). Abingdon:
Routledge.
Carter, C. A., & Zhu, J. (2009). Trade
Liberalization and Agricultural Terms of Trade in China: Price Scissors
Revisited. Retrieved from http://ageconsearch.umn.edu:
http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/51636/2/paper%20746.pdf
Dowling, M., & Wignaraja, G. (2006, July). Central
Asia’s Economy: Mapping Future Prospects to 2015. Retrieved from
http://www.silkroadstudies.org:
http://www.silkroadstudies.org/new/docs/Silkroadpapers/0607Wignaraja.pdf
Hare, D. (2008). The Origins and Influence of Land
Property Rights in Vietnam. Development Policy Review, 339-363.
Hossain, M., Ut, T. T., & Janaiah, A. (2003,
June 21-27). Vietnam's Experience with Hybrid Rice. Economic and Political
Weekly, pp. 2523-2529.
Knight, M., Loayza, N., & Villanueva, D. (1993,
September). Testing the Neoclassical Theory of Economic Growth: A Panel Data
Approach. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, pp. 512-541.
Li, H. (2009). In Village China Under Socialism
and Reform (pp. 185-207). California: Stanford University Press.
Mathijs, E., & Swinnen, J. F. (1998, October).
The Economics of Agricultural Decollectivization in East Central Europe and
the Former Soviet Union. Economic Development and Cultural Change, pp.
1-26.
Naughton, B. (2007). The Chinese Economy:
Transition and Growth. London: The MIT Press.
Rakshit, S. (2011, October). Capital
Intensification, Productivity and Exchange - A Class-Based Analysis of
Agriculture in West Bengal in the Current Millennium. Journal of Agrarian
Change, pp. 505-535.
Rozelle, S., & Swinnen, J. F. (2004). Success
and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal
of Economic Literature, 404-456.
Sušjan, A., & Redek, T. (2008, June).
Uncertainty and Growth in Transition Economies. Review of Social Economy,
pp. 209-234.
Swinnen, J. F., Van Herck, K., & Vranken, L.
(2009). AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES. Retrieved 3
11, 2012, from http://www.choicesmagazine.org:
http://www.choicesmagazine.org/magazine/pdf/article_93.pdf
Tyers, R. (1994). Economic Reform in Europe and
the Former Soviet Union: Implications for Internation food Markets.
Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute.
Wolz, A., & Duong, P. B. (2008, December). The
Transformation of Agricultural Producer Cooperatives - The Case of Vietnam.
Retrieved from http://departments.agri.huji.ac.il:
http://departments.agri.huji.ac.il/economics/en/events/p-wolz.pdf
Appendices:
Country
|
average growth of output in agriculture, over
18 years of transition from Socialism
|
China
|
5.554075
|
Kazakhstan
|
-0.84866
|
Kyrgyzstan
|
1.334624
|
Russian Federation
|
-1.53401
|
Tajikistan
|
2.212311
|
Turkmenistan
|
5.205089
|
Uzbekistan
|
2.596304
|
Viet Nam
|
5.200102
|
FAOSTAT note:
Value of gross production has been
compiled by multiplying gross production in physical terms by output prices
at farm gate. Thus, value of production measures production in monetary terms
at the farm gate level. Since intermediate uses within the agricultural
sector (seed and feed) have not been subtracted from production data, this
value of production aggregate refers to the notion of "gross
production".
Value of gross production is provided in both current
and constant terms and is expressed in US dollars and Standard Local Currency
(SLC). The current value of production measures value in the prices relating
to the period being measured. Thus, it represents the market value of food
and agricultural products at the time they were produced. Knowing this figure
is helpful in understanding exactly what was happening within a given economy
at that point in time. Often, this information can help explain economic
trends that emerged in later periods and why they took place. Value of
production in constant terms is derived using the average prices of a
selected year or years, known as the base period. Constant price series can
be used to show how the quantity or volume of products has changed, and are
often referred to as volume measures. The ratio of the current and constant
price series gives a measure of price movements.
US dollar figures for value of gross production are
converted from local currencies using official exchange rates as prevailing
in the respective years. The SLC of a country is the local currency
prevailing in the latest year. Expressing data series in one uniform currency
is useful because it avoids the influence of revaluation in local currency,
if any, on value of production.
Please note that livestock value of production is
measured in terms of indigenous meat.
|
[1] I
calculate that over 18 years the average growth rate of Turkmenistan in
agricultural output is 5.2%, and China, if taking the start of collectivisation
as 1978, after 18 years the average growth rate of agricultural output is 5.6%.
Impressive rates of growth for Turkmenistan, or impressive for China to beat
agricultural output of an oil exporting nation?
No comments:
Post a Comment